Treceți la conținutul principal

Extraterritorial Voting as a Form of Emigrants’ Political Participation (Author: Mark Mazureanu)


In this post I will try to answer the question whether the emigrants constitute a powerful mechanism to exercise political pressure on the domestic elites to bring institutional reforms and political representation home considering the emigrants right to take part in domestic elections. The emigrants's non-electoral power is discussed in the previous post. I will answer the raised question by resuming the predominant scholarly arguments based on individual observations or large and small N analyzes. This material can be used to understand to which extent Moldova emigration has the possibility to influence the political process home, considering their rights to take part in elections.

Research on extraterritorial voting is still scarce considering that historically only few states granted their emigrants the right to vote while abroad (Barry, 2006; Rubio-Marin, 2006; Tager, 2006; Waldrauch, 2003). Yet, in the last decade, states have increasingly created frameworks for dual nationality to allow their expats to take part, to some extent, in elections (Ellis et al., 2007). According to Portes (1999), “[t]his policy represents a remarkable departure from earlier times, when emigrants were almost regarded as defectors and where naturalization in another country entailed the automatic loss of the original citizenship” (p. 467). Nowadays there are 115 out of 214 states that already enfranchised their co-nationals abroad (Fierro et al., 2007). Moreover, there are cases when for political reasons states grant citizenship, and with them electoral rights to their co-nationals in other states, as in the case of Romania granting citizenship to Moldovans, or Russia granting citizenship to large numbers of citizens from the post-Soviet republics. If until recently governments treated their emigrants only as sources of remittances (Itzigsohn et al., 1999), currently they have increasingly “started to perceive their expatriate communities as a source of investments, entrepreneurial initiatives, markets for home country companies and even political representation abroad or right to advance its geo-political interests in the region” (Portes, 1999, p. 467). This is an important change because in highly competitive elections, migrants can have the final say on electoral outcomes. This was the case in the Romanian presidential elections in 2014, and in Moldovan parliamentary elections in 2009 and 2014.

There is a strong debate in the literature whether emigrants should generally preserve their right to vote from abroad. Many states with large emigrant communities abroad undertook the necessary reforms to offer their emigrants the right for dual citizenship with formal political representation of their expatriates in Parliament and some governmental agencies  (Lessinger, 1992; Mahler, 1998; Guarnizo & Smith 1998). The arguments range from procedural, to nationalistic, utilitarian, and ethical justifications. Supporters claim that since migrants contribute to the economic and socio-cultural development of their homeland they have the right to preserve their political privileges to influence home politics through voting (Itzigsohn, 2000; Wuker, 2004). This argument is also supported by the advancement of modern technologies that facilitate the process of voting from abroad (Barry, 2006; Baubock, 2006; Mercurio & Williams, 2004; Spiro, 2003, 2006). The ethno-nationalist argument claims that allowing emigrants to vote keeps them closer to the motherland, and empowers their status abroad (Baubock, 2006). Granting the right to vote also improves the democratic image of a state on the international arena (Levitt & la Dehesa, 2003).
Opponents claim that extra-territorial voting offers the mandate on decision-making to those subjects who do not support the consequences of their decisions. Thus they take uninformed or less informed decisions about the electorate candidates since they are not the ones to bare the consequences. This principle violates one of the main ground rules of democracy, “the governors must also be the governed” because emigrants are participating through their vote in the process of governance without feeling its impact since they are abroad (Fitzgerald, 2006; Lopez-Guerra, 2005; Rubio-Marin, 2006; Baubock 2005; Blais et al., 2001). The normative arguments state that the extraterritorial vote might bring disproportional representation, especially valid for states with large diaspora abroad (Vertovec, 2005). Baubock (2006) argues in this regard that, “A reasonable expectation that expatriate voters may outnumber domestic ones provides a strong argument against enfranchising the former and for restricting the franchise to temporary absentees” (p. 2444).

The debate on emigrants’ voting autonomy raises the question whether emigrants can freely formulate and express their electoral priorities, or these are influenced and controlled by the power elites from their countries of origin. Some claim that despite receiving the right to vote in national elections, governments can control emigrants’ electoral choices. Smith (2008) argues that in many cases before enfranchising emigrants the power secures mechanisms to retain control over the flow of their votes. By analyzing the evolution of the enfranchisement process in three consecutive elections in Mexico, Smith concludes that the ruling elite established a number of bureaucratic institutions specifically dedicated to administer the state relationship with diaspora. These establishments in Mexico are the Program for Mexican Communities Abroad, Institute for Mexican Abroad, and the National Council for Mexican Communities Abroad. These institutions were delegated to create the official channels of communication between the state and emigrant communities. Thus the state obtains a strong hand in guiding emigrants’ priorities.

Another argument contends that by allowing governments to formalize the organizational activity for diaspora, makes it easier for governments to control how the diaspora creates and delivers its political message. As a result, the granted right to vote does not challenge the governing elites since the state shapes emigrants’ views on home politics through modeled institutional mechanisms (Schedler, 2007). The challengers of this view show that reasoning is not universal and there are cases that disprove the argument. Despite the large role played by the Mexican administrative chapters organized for the diaspora at home and abroad, emigrants managed to overturn the dominant party by massively voting for the non-incumbent candidate during the presidential elections in 2006 (Cornelius et al., 2007). In other cases, such as the Italian and Cape Verdean elections in 2006 (Baubock, 2006), and the presidential elections in Romania in 2014, emigrants played a decisive role in overturning the incumbents.

Assuming the high uncertainty of impact, power elites are very cautious in enfranchising their emigrants. In some cases the legislation has been approved, but not yet implemented, as in the case of Dominican Republic (Levitt, 2001). A similar situation was in Mexico. First, the legislation was voted, and later amended several times thus restricting the right to vote for some segments of emigrants (Saldana, 1999). This was the case because the dominant Partido Revolucionario Institucional  (PRI) was influencing the legislative process at the time. The majority of Mexicans in California however were anti-PRI (Quinones, 1999). By extending the right to vote, the incumbents were immanently empowering the opposition.
Governments can also use their political leverage to attract the loyalty of emigrants abroad. Granting political representation to emigrants at the national level is a tool to sway emigrants’ allegiance. The granted political representation is the cost paid by the elites in exchange for emigrants’ political and economic support in elections (Roberts et al., 1999; Glick Schiller & Fouron, 1999). Some political elites implemented reforms that institutionalized the migrants’ long-distance political participation. One of the first diaspora payoffs took place in 1990 when Croatian diaspora contributed four million dollars to the electoral campaign of Fanjo Tudjman. Upon winning elections, the diaspora was rewarded with 12 out of 120 seats representation (Vertovec, 1999). Collyer 2014 show also that in 13 states emigrants have obtained the right to have extra-territorial legislative representations. Another instance is the Dominican PLD that offered three legislative seats to representatives of the Dominican transnational community. The elected representatives had to act on behalf of both their home-region and the interests of the emigrants living abroad at governmental level (Itzigsohn et al., 1999). The Colombian case displays a similar pattern where an individual living abroad with dual citizenship was voted to represent a Colombian region in the national congress (Guarnizo et al., 1999).

The provision of improved socioeconomic public services is another form of reward paid by governments to thank emigrants for their electoral allegiance. For instance, Laguerre (1998) describes how the Haitian government created the Ministry of Diasporic Affairs to coordinate relations between the Haitian government and its diaspora. In Mexico, Programa Paisano aims to reduce bureaucratic problems for returning migrants (Guarnizo, 1998). The Dominican government worked out a range of policies to ease the migrant return and the long-distance transnationalism. A special custom policy introduced under the President Leonel Fernández allows return migrants to bring their possessions to the island without paying taxes. The returning Dominicans were entitled to purchase at a discount price housing units in Santo Domingo built by the government specifically for returnees. Also, a special agreement was set up with the American banks to secure long-term loans for returning emigrants under president Fernandez. The Salvadorian government crafted a transnational credit union that supports migrants in the United States and their relatives back in El Salvador to secure loans (Hamilton & Chinchilla, 1999). All these and many other measures constitute clear signals sent by the government to their migrants abroad (Levitt, 2001). These can be treated as an invitation to return home but also a demand for continuous loyalty. Portes (1999) however, concludes the following:

“From these policies, it is clear that sending governments do not want their immigrants to return, but rather to achieve a secure status in the wealthy nations to which they have moved and from which they can make sustained economic and political contributions in the name of patriotism and home town loyalties” (p. 467).

Some scholars who have examined the electoral power of emigrants’ vote conclude that emigrant enfranchisement rarely makes a significant difference for national politics. Ostergaard-Nielsen (2003) claims that the emigrant vote represents more of a symbolic act as it formally reasserts the existence of a constitutive tie between a state and its citizens, wherever they reside. This symbolic character of emigrant vote shows the insignificant impact it can have on home politics. Moreover the benefits emigrants get from voting are also very little. This makes them lose interest in taking part in the voting routine. Although emigrants are enfranchised they exert little interest to take part in elections. According to statistical results on voting patterns of newly enfranchised Mexican emigrants in the United States, Waldinger and Soehl (2013) notice that only an insignificant group of Mexican emigrants registered to take part in elections since 2005 when they were granted this right. Moreover, just half of those registered came to express their vote. Another explanation of low participation rate of Mexicans in elections is the lack of previous electoral experience or the low level of political culture (Waldinger & Soehr, 2013).

The low electoral participation among emigrants is however not characteristic only to emigrants that lack electoral traditions. The same lack of interest to vote is observed among the French expatriates who have the right to vote from abroad since 1946. Despite the presence of a strong political culture among French expatriates, the turnout is way below the level of electoral participation in France (Cariot & Clave, 2009). In the Ruget and Usmanalieva (2011) study the authors assessed the patterns of participation among Kyrgyz emigrants and returnees in the 2009 presidential elections. The respondents were asked if they used their right to vote and how much they value having this right while abroad. Only one fourth of respondents declared that they took part in elections. And only one fourth of those who took part in elections voted from abroad. All others voted while at home. This data shows an extremely low electoral participation of Tajik emigrants. Boccagni (2011) also reported that only a tiny fraction of 1.6 percent of Ecuadorian migrants residing abroad showed up to vote in 2006 elections from the estimated 20 percent population with an electoral right. 

A similarly low interest can be observed among emigrants in regards to other forms of political participation beyond electoral participation. Based on data from the 2006 Latino National Survey, Fraga et al. (2006) show that 34 percent of foreign-born respondents pay no attention to home country politics, while 23 percent stated that they pay only little attention. Moreover, only 4 percent of respondents in the 2008 National Asian American Survey said they participate in activities dealing with their country of origin (Wong et al., 2011). Among Latin American emigrants, 94 percent of Colombian, Dominican and Salvadoran expatriates surveyed in the Comparative Immigrant Entrepreneurship Project declared that they never took part in campaigns to support any of their home country political candidates. Concurrently, 96 percent declared that they never made a donation to support any of the electoral campaigns.

The low interest in political affairs among emigrants is due to reduced levels of trust and knowledge about institutionalized social and political activity, and the lack of an institutionalized venue where to organize beyond the usual circle of friends and relatives, is the conclusion Ruget and Usmanalieva (2011) came to in their study on electoral behavior of Tajik emigrants. This type of political apathy is also noticed by Fox (2009) who claims, in fact, that by not engaging in political life does not mean that migrants stay apathetic to the political reality. The emigrants create an alternative form of engagement by networks of ‘translocal citizenship’. The transnational citizenship is a creation of a specific international community that acts without paying much attention to the political life of countries of origin.
Political parties also show different forms of interactions with their emigrant communities. Some parties become increasingly interested in getting emigrants involved in domestic politics. The literature illustrates numerous cases when political parties opened branch offices in migrant settlements (Levit, 2001; Kapur, 2007; Graham, 1996; McDonnell, 1997; Itzigsohn et al., 1999). In this context, political campaigns undertaken by political candidates became a routine activity especially among the Latin American countries. These campaigns usually aim to capture emigrants’ attention, gather their votes in the upcoming elections, and recruit financial donations from these communities (Levit, 2001). The political and financial support provided by emigrants is especially valuable for opposition parties. In the case of Dominican Republic, the migrants’ financial contributions constitute nearly 15 percent of major Dominican parties’ annual fundraising revenue (Graham, 1996). Levitt (2001) reports that approximately 10 to 30 percent of the Dominican PRD’s budget and 50 percent of the budget for the 1994 Dominican presidential campaign came from migrant contributions. Numerous scholars claim that despite long standing residence abroad, emigrants continue to keep themselves engaged in home politics (Kearney, 1991, 1995; Grasmuck & Pessar, 1991; Smith, 1994; Kyle, 2000).

There is also a large body of literature analyzing the emigrants’ impact on the quality of political and economic institutions in their countries of origin. Docquier et al. (2010) analyze the impact of skilled vs. unskilled migration on the quality of political institutions. Based on quantitative data analysis of migration to the OECD countries in the period 1975–2000, they conclude that low-skilled emigration positively affected the quality of political institutions in their home countries. Emigration of the highly skilled, on the contrary, brings positive effects only in the long-term. Li and McHale (2009) also look at the mechanisms through which skilled migrants can affect the political and economic institutions in their countries of origin. Their results show positive effects on the quality of political institutions. Skilled migration contributed to political stability, voice, and accountability in sending countries.

Emigration of the skilled, however, negatively affects the quality of economic institutions by decreasing the levels of government accountability, regulatory quality, rule of law, and control of corruption. After a detailed statistical analysis of panel data for 111 countries over the period of 1986–2010, Berdiev et al. (2013) conclude that the influx of remittances brought by emigrants increases the level of corruption in the country of origin. The correlation between corruption and remittances is conditioned by the fact that higher remittances lead to an increase in the GDP per capita. Hence, when people are poorer there is nothing to extort through corrupt behavior. And vice-versa, when the level of income increases it opens up greater avenues for corruption.
Kapur (2007) also claims that the loss of human capital through migration can adversely affect the country’ institutions. The prospect for emigration makes the younger less eager to invest in skills relevant for the local institutions. Instead, they invest in skills that are more internationally marketable. This fact increases the demand for such specializations as programmers, engineers and decreases those of lawyers and public service workers. Consequently absence of talented individuals negatively affects the supply of institution builders. As a result, the less trained remains the local population the lesser demand they exercise for qualitative institutions (Kapur & McHale, 2006).

No conclusion…

Bibliography:

·      Barry, Kim. "Home and away: The construction of citizenship in an emigration context." NYUL Rev. 81 (2006): 11.
·      Baubock, Rainer. "Stakeholder citizenship and transnational political participation: a normative evaluation of external voting." Fordham L. Rev. 75 (2006): 2393.
·      Berdiev, Aziz N., Yoonbai Kim, and Chun-Ping Chang. "Remittances and corruption." Economics Letters 118.1 (2013): 182-185.
·      Blais, André, Louis Massicotte, and Antoine Yoshinaka. "Deciding who has the right to vote: a comparative analysis of election laws." Electoral studies 20.1 (2001): 41-62.
·      Boccagni, Paolo. "Reminiscences, patriotism, participation: approaching external voting in Ecuadorian immigration to Italy." International Migration 49.3 (2011): 76-98.
·      Cariot, M. Bernard and M. Paul Clave. 2009 Les Francais etablis hors de France: leurs attentes, leur besoins. Conseil Economique, Social, et Environmental. Retrieved from: http://www.ladocumentationfrancaise.fr/var/storage/rapports-publics/094000062/0000.pdf
·      Collyer, Michael. "Inside out? Directly elected ‘special representation’of emigrants in national legislatures and the role of popular sovereignty." Political Geography 41 (2014): 64-73.
·      Docquier, F., & Lodigiani, E. (2010). Skilled migration and business networks. Open Economies Review, 21(4), 565-588.
·      Ellis, Andrew, et al. Voting from abroad: The International IDEA handbook. International Idea, 2007.
·      Fierro, Carlos Navarro, Isabel Morales, and Maria Gratschew. "External voting: a comparative overview." Voting From Abroad: The International IDEA Handbook, ed. IDEA & IFE, IDEA & IFE, Stockholm and Mexico (2007): 11-35.
·      Fitzgerald, David. "Rethinking emigrant citizenship." NYUL Rev. 81 (2006).
·      Fox, Jonathan A. "Exit Followed by Voice: Mapping Mexico’s Emerging Migrant Civil Society." Center for Global, International and Regional Studies (2009).
·      Fraga, Luis R., et al. "Latino National Survey (LNS), 2006 [Computer file]. ICPSR20862-v1. Miami, FL: Geoscape International [producer], 2006." Ann Arbor, MI: Inter-university Consortium for Political and Social Research [distributor] (2008): 05-27.
·      Graham, Pamela M. "3: Reimagining the Nation and Defining the District: Dominican Migration and Transnational Politics." Center for Migration Studies special issues 13.4 (1996): 91-125.
·      Grasmuck, Sherri, and Patricia R. Pessar. Between two islands: Dominican international migration. Univ of California Press, 1991.
·      Hamilton, N. and N. Stoltz Chinchilla (1999) ‘New organizing strategies and transnational networks of Guatemalan and Salvadorans in Los Angeles’, Paper presented at the University of California Comparative Immigration and Integration Program Research Workshop, San Diego, CA.
·      Itzigsohn, José, et al. "Mapping Dominican transnationalism: narrow and broad transnational practices." Ethnic and racial studies 22.2 (1999): 316-339.
·      Itzigsohn, José. "Immigration and the boundaries of citizenship: the institutions of immigrants' political transnationalism." International Migration Review (2000): 1126-1154.
·      Kapur, Devesh, and John McHale. "Cosmopolitanism and the’Brain Drain’." Ethics and International Affairs 20.3 (2006): 305-20.
·      Kapur, Devesh. "The Janus face of diasporas." Diasporas and Development (2007): 89-118.
·      Kearney, Michael. "Borders and Boundaries of State and Self at the End of Empire." Journal of Historical Sociology 4.1 (1991): 52-74.
·      Kearney, Michael. "The local and the global: The anthropology of globalization and transnationalism." Annual review of anthropology (1995): 547-565.
·      Kyle, D. (2000). Transnational peasants: Migrations, networks, and ethnicity in Andean Ecuador. JHU Press.
·      Lessinger, Johanna. "Investing or Going Home? A Transnational Strategy among Indian Immigrants in the United Statesa." Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences 645.1 (1992): 53-80.
·      Levitt, Peggy, and Rafael De la Dehesa. "Transnational migration and the redefinition of the state: variations and explanations." Ethnic and racial studies 26.4 (2003): 587-611.
·      Levitt, Peggy. "Transnational migration: taking stock and future directions." Global networks 1.3 (2001): 195-216.
·      Li, Xiaoyang, and John McHale. "Emigrants and institutions." University of Michigan, Ann Arbor, and National University of Ireland, Galway (2009).
·      López‐Guerra, C. (2005). Should expatriates vote?. Journal of Political Philosophy, 13(2), 216-234.
·      Mahler, Sarah J. "Theoretical and empirical contributions toward a research agenda for transnationalism." Transnationalism from below 6 (1998): 64-100.
·      McCann, James, Wayne Cornelius, and David Leal. "Mexico’s VotoRemoto and the Potential for Transnational Civic Engagement among Mexican Expatriates." American Political Science Association. 2006.
·      Mercurio, Bryan, and George Williams. "Australian Diaspora and the Right to Vote, The." UW Austl. L. Rev. 32 (2004): 1.
·      Ostergaard-Nielsen, Eva. "The politics of migrants' transnational political practices." International migration review 37.3 (2003): 760-786.
·      Portes, Alejandro, Luis E. Guarnizo, and Patricia Landolt. "The study of transnationalism: pitfalls and promise of an emergent research field." Ethnic and racial studies 22.2 (1999): 217-237.
·      Quiñones, S. "Death of voting-abroad bill in Mexico was simple math." San Diego Union Tribune 3 (1999).
·      Roberts, Bryan R., Reanne Frank, and Fernando Lozano-Ascencio. "Transnational migrant communities and Mexican migration to the US." Ethnic and racial studies 22.2 (1999): 238-266.
·      Rubio-Marin, Ruth. "Transnational politics and the democratic nation-state: normative challenges of expatriate voting and nationality retention of emigrants." NYUL Rev. 81 (2006): 117.
·      Schedler, Andreas. "The mobilization of distrust." Journal of Democracy 18.1 (2007): 88-102.
·      Schiller, Nina Glick, and Georges E. Fouron. "Terrains of blood and nation: Haitian transnational social fields." Ethnic and racial studies 22.2 (1999): 340-366.
·      Smith, Michael Peter, and L. Guarnizo. "Transnationalism from below: Comparative urban and community research." New Brunswick: Transaction Publishers (1998).
·      Smith, Michael Peter. "Can you imagine? Transnational migration and the globalization of grassroots politics." Social Text (1994): 15-33.
·      Spiro, Peter J. "Perfecting political diaspora." NYUL Rev. 81 (2006): 207.
·      Spiro, Peter J. "Political rights and dual nationality." IN MARTIN, DA & HAILBRONNER, K.(Eds.) Rights (2003).
·      Tager, Michael. "Expatriates and elections." Diaspora: A Journal of Transnational Studies 15.1 (2006): 35-60.
·      Vertovec, Steven. The political importance of diasporas. Centre on Migration, Policy & Society, 2005.
·      Waldinger, Roger, and Thomas Soehl. "The bounded polity: The limits to Mexican emigrant political participation." Social forces 91.4 (2013): 1239-1266.
·      Waldrauch, H. (2003). Electoral rights for Foreign Nationals: A comparative overview of regulations in 36 countries. National Europe Centre Paper No. 73. Vienna, Austria.
·      Wong, Janelle, et al. Asian American political participation: Emerging constituents and their political identities. Russell Sage Foundation, 2011.
·      Wucker, M. (2004). Remittances: the perpetual migration machine. World policy journal, 21(2), 37-46.


Comentarii

Postări populare de pe acest blog

What drives ethnic conflicts forward?

Which school of though better explains the causes of ethnic violence? Introduction The nature of ethnic violence has been always generating debates among scholars coming from the fields of comparative politics and international relations. The question discussed in this post will contrast several types of arguments, the rationalist argument that sees the ethnic conflict as a rational result of group and individual behavior (Steinberg 1981; Glazer & Moynihan 1975) with the premordialist argument that observe the ethnic violence as an inevitable clash based on innate antagonisms of contending groups (Smith 1986; Kaplan 1993), the constructivist, and the symbolist politics. I will try to project which of the theory provides a better answer to the questions: whether conflicts among different ethnicities are natural phenomena or and what are the factors that trigger the escalation of ethnic violence? Rational choice theory perceives ethnic conflict

Profanarea simbolicii UE sau nu?

Profanarea simbolicii UE sau nu? Recent trecând prin preajma sediul Partidului Democrat am auzit o fîlfîitură care mi-a atras atenția. Mi-am îndreptat vederea - erau drapelele Moldovei arborate deolaltă cu cele ale Uniunii Europene. Trebuie să recunoaștem ele se privesc perfect pe fundalul signel PDM. Trandafiri roșii pe fon albastru combinate cu drapelul albastru UE este o asortare cu adevărat perfectă de culori care inspiră încredere și pace. Aici însă ne oprim, precum fiecare istorie conține și un DAR. Precum a zis bine cineva, totul ce este mentionat pînă la dar este doar umplutură de aceia vom trece la partea de după DAR. Fără mari tertipuri legale știm că folosirea simbolicii unor anumitor entități politice presupune împărtășirea valorilor acestor instituții. Mai mult ca atît răspîndirea acestor valori prin arborarea simbolicii vine la pachet cu anumite responsabilități morale față de instituția a căror simbolică o arborăm. Pe de altă parte, autodeclararea de a

Why don't we chose the right version in the election day?

Every person wants to live a healthy life endowed with bountiful economic benefits and social liberties, proud of his own achievements and respect of his neighbors. This description can be attributed to any being disregarding of his socio-political orientations or his geo-political preferences. This truth has a simple explanation - the humans are actors driven by rationality. That is why when it comes to express their political preferences they will chose only the best from the offered option, that comes with maximum benefits for him personally, his family members and the community/society he lives in. This system however can work only in a democratic society where different political options compete among themselves on a stage with an open and free public tribune. Where the political field is even and gives equal chances to all political options. When, the microphone installed on the public tribune invites everyone and everyone has the right to speak freely. And fin